Mathematical Growth Models

Some of the more important ideas about economic growth are based on mathematical models. This lesson looks at some of these.

The Malthusian Model

Before 1800, technological progress was relatively slow. The result was that output per worker hardly increased at all, but population grew. In 1798, Thomas Malthus wrote an essay on population that presented a pessimistic picture of economic growth. He said that when food is ample, population grows exponentially. Because there are diminishing returns to labor in food production, exponential population growth leads to starvation, and population falls again.

Here is a numerical example of a two-equation Malthusian model.

[food production] Yt = 1000 + Lt

This t generation's food production, Yt, increases linearly with this generation's labor supply (population) Lt.

However, the next (t+1) generation's labor supply or population growth Lt+1increases with the square of this generation's ratio of food to population.

[population growth] Lt+1 = 600 + 100*(Yt/Lt)2

You can solve these two equations for values of Y and L that will be stable. These are called the equilibrium values. In this case, they are 2000 for Y and 1000 for L. If L is 1000, then according to the food production equation, Y will be 2000. If Y is 2000, then population will grow to be 1000.

What happens if we start out with 2000 units of food, but disease causes the population to fall to 900? You can use the calculator below to see what happens if population starts out too low or too high. If you click on "calculate" the economy will move forward in time one generation. Keep clicking on "calculate" and you will see Y and L oscillate back and forth until they converge to their equilibrium values. You can try starting out with different values of Y and L and see the convergence process from different starting points.

Next, suppose that we get better technology in food production, so that the food production equation becomes

Yt = 1200 + Lt

What happens to the equilibrium values of Y, L, and Y/L? Use the calculator below to find out. Keep clicking on calculate until the values stop changing.

What is the equilibrium level of food? What is the equilibrium level for the population? What is the equilibrium ratio of food to population?

At first, with the population at 1000, the technological improvement brings food production to 2200, and the ratio of food to population rises to 2.200. However, in the final equilibrium, because of population increases, the ratio of food to population is only 2.136 ie. 2256/1056. This is the Malthusian effect by which population growth dissipates technological advances. In fact, prior to 1800, the Malthusian effect was so strong that there was very little progress in average output per capita; instead, nearly all of the inventions and technological advances until 1800 served primarily to increase population.

Capital Accumulation

When the Industrial Revolution broke out of the Malthusian trap, economies began to accumulate capital goods. In order to accumulate capital, you have to save. This means that you cannot consume all of your output.

Start with a constant level of output, Y, and no growth. Suppose that capital depreciates at a rate of 5% per year or that the capital stock has a lifetime of 20 years. If we want to provision money every year in order to keep the level of capital constant we have to replace 5% of the capital stock each year.

This means that saving, S, must equal 5% of the capital stock.

[1] S = 5%K

We think of the savings rate, s, as the ratio of savings to income, S/Y. Writing equation [1] in terms of s, we have

[2] s = S/Y = 5%(K/Y)

where all we did was divide the previous equation by Y on both sides. What this equation says is that in order to maintain constant output, we need a savings rate that equals the rate of depreciation 5% times the capital/output ratio. If we want to have high labor productivity, we need a high ratio of capital to output, and therefore we need a high saving rate. Thus, we expect to find a relationship between countries with high saving rates and countries with high productivity, and this is indeed what Brad DeLong found when he indicated that countries with high productivity tend to have saving rates over 20 percent.

Suppose now that we want the capital stock to grow at a rate of 2% per year. In that case, we need

[3] S = 5%K + 2%K

Or, in terms of s and K/Y, we need

[4] s = 5%(K/Y) + 2%(K/Y) = 7%(K/Y)

If we use the symbol d to represent depreciation, the symbol k to stand for the capital-output ratio K/Y, and the symbol x to stand for the growth rate of capital DK/K, then we can write

[5] s = dk + xk

To see how the saving rate affects the growth rate of capital, we can solve [5] for x, the growth rate of capital.

[6] x = s/k - d

If the labor force is growing at a rate n, then the capital/labor ratio will grow at the rate of x-n. For example, suppose that the saving rate s is 25%, that te capital/output ratio k is 2.5, the depreciation rate d is 5%, and the growth rate of the labor force n is 1%. Then we have

[7] x - n = s/ - d - n = 25%/2.5 - 5% -1% = 4%

which says that the capital/labor ratio grows at 4% per year. (In a moment, when I discuss balanced growth, I will argue that this is not a reasonable long-term growth rate for the capital/labor ratio.)

Labor Productivity

We are interested in the growth rate of labor productivity, Y/L. To look at productivity, we return to the production function that we used in the growth accounting lesson.

[8] (Y/L) = (K/L)0.25E0.75

where E is the efficiency of labor. When we took logs of both sides, we obtained an equation for the growth rate of productivity. If y is the growth rate of output and n is the growth rate of the labor force, then the growth rate of productivity is y-n. Letting g be the symbol for the growth rate of E, the efficiency of labor, we have

[9] y - n = 0.25(x - n) + .75g

When we made numerical assumptions in equation [7], we found that x-n = .04. Plugging this into equation [9] and assuming that the growth rate of the efficiency of labor, g, is .02, we have

[10] y - n = 0.25(.04) + .75(.02) = .025

Thus, the assumptions about saving rate, depreciation, and so forth imply growth in labor productivity of 2.5% per year.

Balanced Growth

Economists define a balanced growth path as a path along which capital and output grow at the same rate. The alternatives to a balanced growth path are not sustainable. If capital grows more slowly than output, then the capital stock will eventually drop to zero. If capital grows more quickly than output, then the share of output that you set aside for capital goods will increase until you reach the point where the amount available for consumption is zero.

Looking at equation [9], the only way that x and y can be equal is if

[11] g = x - n

That is, for balanced growth, the growth rate of the efficiency of labor must be matched by the growth rate of capital minus the growth rate of the labor force.

The requirement for balanced growth implies that there is only one sustainable ratio of capital to ouput. That is, there is only one ratio of capital to output, k that is consistent with a balanced growth path. Using equations [11] and [7] we have

[12] g = x - n = s/k - d - n

We can solve this equation for a balanced-growth value for k, given the other parameters. Using s = .25, g = .02, n = .01 and d = .05, we have

[13] k = s/(g + n + d) = .25/(.02+.01+.05) = 3.125

Therefore, the balanced-growth capital-output ratio is 3.125. If the capital-output ratio happens to be above this level, the savings rate is not high enough to maintain it, and the ratio will tend to fall back to 3.125. Conversely, if the capital-output ratio happens to start out below the balanced-growth level, the savings rate is high enough to generate capital accumulation until the ratio rises back to 3.125. Back at equation [10] when we computed labor productivity growth, we had assumed earlier an arbitrary capital-output ratio of 2.5. Now, we know that this is not a balanced-growth ratio given the saving rate, depreciation rate, and other assumed parameters. Using the balanced-growth ratio of 3.125 in equation [7] gives

[7'] x - n = .25/3.125 - .05 - .01 = .02

Putting this into [10], we have

[10'] y - n = .25(.02) + .75(.02) = .02

What we have found is that on a balanced growth path, output per worker and capital per worker grow at the same rate as the efficiency of labor. In our example, this is 2% per year.

Summary

Let us review what we have learned from mathematical growth models.

For the Malthusian model:

  1. Whenever the food supply expands, population grows exponentially.

  2. The economy has an equilibrium in which population stays constant.

  3. If the equilibrium is disturbed, population will oscillate. A small generation enjoying a high ratio of food to population will reproduce excessively, leading to a large generation with a low ratio of food to population. This large generation will reproduce minimally, leading to a small generation, etc. As the magnitude of the oscillations diminishes (if indeed they do dampen), the economy goes back to its equilibrium.

  4. Increases in productivity will lead to less than proportionate increases in output per worker. Instead, population expansion and diminishing returns will dissipate much of the technological improvement.

For the balanced-growth model of capital accumulation:

  1. The growth rate of the economy is equal to the growth rate of the efficiency of labor. Capital per worker and output per worker both grow at this rate.

  2. The savings rate affects the level of productivity and the level of the capital/output ratio. The higher the savings rate, the higher the capital/output ratio and the higher the level of productivity.


The Harrod-Domar Growth Model

Summary

The Harrod-Domar growth model gives some insights into the dynamics of growth. We want a method of determining an equilibrium growth rate g for the economy. Let Y be GDP and S be savings.

The level of savings is a function of the level of GDP, say S = sY. The level of capital K needed to produce an output Y is given by the equation K=σY where σ deignates the capital-output ratio K/Y.

Investment is a very important variable for the economy because Investment has a dual role. Investment I represents an important component of the demand for the output of the economy as well as the increase in capital stock. Thus Investment I is DK = σDY.

For equilibrium there must be a balance between the supply of savings and the demand for increasing the capital stock. This balance reduces to I = S.

Thus, I = ΔK = σΔY

and I = S = sY

so
σΔY = sY.

Therefore the equilibrium rate of growth ΔY/Y which we call g, is given by:

ΔY/Y = s/σ = g

In other words, the equilibrium growth rate of output is equal to the ratio of the savings rate "s" and the capital-output ratio σ or K/Y. This is a very significant result. It tells us how the economy can grow so that growth in the capacity of the economy to produce is matched by the demand for the economy's output.

Consider this numerical illustration. Suppose the economy is currently operating at a capacity production level of 1000 per year and has a capital-output ratio σ=K/Y=3. This means the capital stock is 3000. Assume the savings rate s=30% and the propensity to consume output Y is 70%. Savings rate "s" includes business and public savings as well as household savings.

The Harrod-Domar growth model tells that the equilibrium growth rate is g = 30%/3 = 10%; i.e., the economy can grow at 10% per year. We can now check this result with actual series of statistics.

At the current GDP of 1000 the level of saving is 30%*1000=300. The growth in GDP is 10%*1000 = 100 and with a capital-output ratio of 3 the additional capital required to produce the additional output is 3*100=300. This is the investment required in order to increase capacity by the right amount and, sure enough, this happens to be equal to the amount of saving available in the economy.

But we must made sure there is adequate aggregate demand next year to absorb the production of 1100. At that level of income, consumer demand is 70% of 1100, so 770. The level of investment the next year under the assumed equilibrium growth conditions is derived as above. The 10% growth of production Y of 1100 is 110 which, with a capital-output ratio of 3, requires an increase in capital stock of 330. Thus next year's investment will be 330. This, added to the consumer demand of 770 gives an aggregate demand of 1100. So everything balances.

For contrast, let us consider what would happen if the level of current level of investment were to be higher, say 350. This, combined with consumption demand of 700 generates more demand than the capacity of the economy to produce. That excess of investment of 50 induces a demand for an additional 3*50 = 150 units of capital which the economy cannot achieve. There is an irresolvable excess of demand in the economy.

On the other hand, suppose the investment demand fell short of 300, say 250. Now the aggregate demand is only 950, less than the capacity of the economy. If production falls to 950 there is an excess of capital and no need for any investment. Thus aggregate demand fall as investment dropped to zero and consumer demand would drop along with. There would be an irresolvable deficiency of demand.

The equilibrium of the Harrod-Domar model is a razor-edge equilibrium. If the economy deviates from it in either direction there will be an economy calamity.